Ida May Fuller, the first Social Security recipient |
The present skirmish in the Obamacare wars concerns whether those in the individual healthcare insurance market will be able to keep their existing plans. Most people get their health insurance through their employer or through the federal government (i.e. Medicare or Medicaid), but 9% buy it as individuals directly from insurance companies. As Obamacare swings into operation it’s causing many of those individuals – it’s hard to say exactly how many – to lose their plans, forcing them onto more expensive plans. It seems unfair, and it’s proving to be a political disaster for the president, especially considering his repeated promises that this would never happen. Throw in the ongoing fiasco of the federal government’s insurance exchange website and not only does Obamacare begin to seem fundamentally flawed, but – as some kind conservatives have helpfully suggested – so does liberalism itself.
Hardly. As the indispensible Jonathan Chait has
explained in numerous
clarifying
pieces,
if you wish to make sure that (nearly) everyone has adequate health insurance
then there must be some
mechanism for making the young, healthy and affluent help pay for the old,
sick and poor. For example, Obamacare
forces insurance companies to cover people in the individual market with pre-existing
medical conditions, most of whom have been denied coverage or forced to pay
exorbitant premiums. How is that
additional coverage paid for? Partly it
comes from subsidies to poorer individuals from Medicaid, which is, of course, funded
by taxpayers. But Obamacare also raises
the regulatory standards of health insurance plans with the specific intent of forcing healthy
individuals to pay for better plans so that insurers can provide care for more
expensive patients. (It also does so to
protect consumers from unreliable
plans,
like those with lifetime caps and serious lapses in coverage.)
But all this is true of employer-based
health insurance as well; i.e. it forces those who need health care less to pay
for those who need it more (subsidized
by taxpayers). Such plans usually
have a set price, regardless of age, sex or medical status, thus allowing a
large group of people to pay for the small number which will actually need
expensive care. Such risk-pooling is the basis of all health insurance – indeed, of all insurance. Obamacare, as Ezra
Klein says, “basically makes the individual market more like the group markets.” That is, it makes it more redistributive. Yes, redistribution rests at the heart of any
insurance system, public or private. And
we’re all willing to contribute to those systems because the future is
uncertain; even the best actuarial tables cannot predict with any certainty who
will need the benefit of insurance. We
buy fire insurance even though, as Chait so eloquently puts it, “fire insurance
is a bad deal for people whose houses don’t burn.”
But let’s take that one step
further: Redistribution rests at the heart of all liberalism. This is liberalism’s open secret, and one’s view
of this principle makes or breaks one’s support for the entire liberal
welfare project. Every worker pays
Medicare taxes, but Medicare only supports those over 65. Medicaid only covers those below a specified financial
threshold. Even Social Security provides
slightly higher benefits to lower wage workers (relative to their lifetime
income). For political reasons liberals generally
attempt
to disguise the redistributive aspects of their programs; for example, Social
Security taxes are paid into individual accounts. But to modern liberalism a secure retirement
is an individual and social good that humanitarianism simply and firmly
demands. Could we consider ourselves a
just society if there were people who had worked their whole lives who were forced
to retire in destitution? It was exactly
destitution to which all too many workers were consigned by pre-welfare-state laissez-faire capitalism. Relative poverty causes so
much harm, we should feel ashamed if it denied people the requisites of
even a modestly fulfilling life: nourishment, education, decent housing, a
secure retirement and medical care. And
if those with less can’t pay for those minimal goods, then – as long as it’s
practical and sustainable – those with more must foot the bill. This is the essence of modern welfare state
liberalism: Taxing the affluent at higher rates and spending that money on insuring
that working and poor people posses the minimal requirements of civilized
life. (This is the crucial distinction
between welfare liberalism and socialism, which advocates the equalization of most or all social goods; liberalism merely advocates minimal
standards and for a much shorter list of goods.) Redistribution is part of the rationale even
for infrastructure and public institutions, such as roads, bridges, hospitals, universities,
crime control, emergency management.
Such things are generally regarded as benefitting everyone, but they’re
partially funded through progressive taxes, and there are such things as
private highways, private police, etc.
Since conservatives generally
equate what you deserve with what capitalism
allocates to you, they consider any non-capitalist redistribution to be
inherently unjust. Pragmatic
conservatives – quite a rare species! – may tolerate a very short list of
public goods and social insurance programs, but only for the sake of market
efficiency or social comity. But, as conservatives,
they would never concede that anyone has a moral
claim on some good for which he could not pay, such as a poor person who cannot
afford a college education. But if you
accept that there are some goods for which everyone should be forced to pay, even those who will never directly benefit
from those goods, then you have accepted the rationale for the welfare
state. All that’s left at that point is
to argue over which goods should be on the list. Should we have public healthcare but not
public housing? Should we have food
stamps but not public day care? We have
moved from the realm of moral justification to that of policy detail. To be sure, the devil is in the details; even
liberals like Ezra Klein dislike
Obamacare’s employer mandate, for example.
But if you accept, for instance, that people without children should pay
taxes for schools, or people who don’t drive should pay taxes for highways,
then you support the welfare state in
principle. However much you feel the
urge to make moral complaints about liberal social policies, you can reasonably
make only practical or economic ones.
You are a redistributionist.
Accept it.
Most Americans – with their sober
and practical generosity – easily accept the logic of liberalism. That practicality lets them support universal
healthcare in general while still seeing Obamacare’s faults. Most of Obamacare’s complexities and
confusions result from using private institutions – i.e. insurance companies –
for public ends. Thus, its
redistribution involves the regulation of private insurance plans in addition to
the typical liberal funding mechanism of direct taxation. But given the moral urgency of universal
coverage and the redistribution it demands, the only alternative would be a single-payer
scheme, in which the federal government acts as the health insurance
company for all Americans and pays for the system out of progressive
taxes. Once again, we can argue over
policy details, but let’s have the adult version of that argument, in which we
accept the necessity of federal government redistribution. Conservatives may
rail against redistribution in principle, while they lambaste
Obama for cutting Medicare funds. And liberals may tout the benefits of tight
regulations on individual plans while swiftly running from any redistributionist
rhetoric. But, outside the Tea Party’s tightly
sealed ideological ghetto, everyone in America actually supports
redistribution. They support it because human decency demands it. They support it because they know that
someday they may come to need it themselves.
They may consider it a necessary evil or a positive good, but they
understand, intellectually or viscerally, that modern life would be intolerable
without it. That is the open secret not
just of liberal politics, but of all American politics.